[NNagain] some comments on old threads on this list
odlyzko at umn.edu
odlyzko at umn.edu
Tue Oct 31 13:12:43 EDT 2023
In catching up on accumulate emails, some of the early
posts on this list caught my attention, on throttling,
roles of governments and monopolies, and so on. This
is something I have been looking at since I first got
involved in network economics in the late 1990s, and
some folks on this list might be interested in a few
comments.
First of all, although I have been a strong advocate
of net neutrality from the start, half a dozen years
before the term "net neutrality" was coined (in the
context of considering QoS), I concluded that the argument
for it should be more subtle than just resistance to
discrimination. In designing operations and pricing for
an infrastructure, one needs to consider carefully
what that infrastructure is for, and also its costs
and benefits. Discriminatory practices have often been
essential to the provision of a variety of goods and
services. Since railroads have been mentioned on this
list, it might be worth recalling that one of the most
memorable descriptions was written in the 1840s by
Jules Dupuit (the most eminent of the French engineers
who were the first ones to come up with basic concepts
of microeconomics):
It is not because of the few thousand francs which would
have to be spent to put a roof over the third-class
carriages or to upholster the third-class seats that some
company or other has open carriages with wooden benches.
What the company is trying to do is to prevent the
passengers who can pay the second class fare from traveling
third class; it hits the poor, not because it wants to hurt
them, but to frighten the rich. And it is again for the
same reason that the companies, having proved almost cruel
to the third-class passengers and mean to the second-class
ones, become lavish in dealing with first-class passengers.
Having refused the poor what is necessary, they give the
rich what is superfluous.
(You might like to recall this the next time you board a
commercial airplane flight!) It should be emphasized that
Dupuit was not exaggerating. I have evidence that on some
early British railways third-class carriages had no seats
at all, and sometimes passengers had to share the space
with pigs. (There was even a suggestion by a director
of one railway that they should send chimney sweeps with
their equipment in third-class carriages, but I have not
found any evidence that this was ever implemented.)
So discrimination was common, and was accepted, even if
reluctantly. (And so it is today, for example in progressive
taxation, where one dollar is not the same as another, or
in tuition at American colleges, where effective prices
paid by students vary depending on their parents' incomes.)
Nowadays the phrase "charging what the traffic will bear"
has strongly negative connotations. But in the past it
was used to mean that some goods could be charged more,
that a canal or railroad fees for carrying pottery or
steel would be more than fertilizer "could bear," so
one should not charge by weight alone. (This, as might
be expected, led to attempts at evasion, loads of pottery
hidden underneath fertilizer, and so on. Generations
of lawyers thrived on litigating such issues.)
It is important to remember that discrimination was not
necessarily imposed by governments (which typically imposed
limits on it), nor was it always due to monopoly power. As
Alissa Cooper showed in her studies of throttling by
British ISPs about a decade ago, and as was observed
on railroads in the 19th century, increased competition
often led to increased discrimination.
However, differential charging has always been a very
sensitive issue, which is why service and goods providers
have often resorted to "market segmentation," with
different qualities of service, as with railroads and
airlines. The practices that led to the greatest
opposition were those verging on what economists call
"first degree price discrimination," where each individual
is charged the maximum that person is willing to pay.
(By sellers have always strived to approach as close
as they could to first degree price discrimination, and
with modern information technology tools that strip away
anonymity, they are getting closer. Uber is an interest
example, but not the only one.)
That is what led to the first serious federal government
intervention in the conduct of business, the Interstate
Commerce Act of 1887. It forbade various types of
discrimination, but not differential charging for different
types of freight, for example, as those were too important
to be abandoned. In general, historically, discriminatory
practices have been more readily accepted when costs were
high. I have written quite a lot about this, and perhaps
the best survey of the evidence and arguments is in the
paper "Network neutrality, search neutrality, and the
never-ending conflict between efficiency and fairness in
markets" which was published in Review of Network Economics
in 2009,
https://www-users.cse.umn.edu/~odlyzko/doc/rne81.pdf
(This was, as far as I have been able to ascertain, the
first use of the term "search neutrality" in a scholarly
paper, and today search neutrality appears to be a more
pressing issue than net neutrality.)
Hence the argument for net neutrality was based not just
on a general desire for having a free Internet, but also
on the relatively low costs of this infrastructure (and
although it might seem surprising, providing Internet service
is very inexpensive when compared to providing rail services
in the 19th century), and also on the value that this
infrastructure provided. As was pointed out in a paper
at the IEEE Globecom'99 conference, "The current state and
likely evolution of the Internet,"
https://www-users.cse.umn.edu/~odlyzko/doc/globecom99.pdf
the main service that the Internet provided then, and, as is
finally being recognized, provides today, is low transaction
latency. That makes it hard to implement effective non-neutral
policies.
Quite a few other papers and presentation decks on these topics
are available on my home page, and they have references to
much of the related literature.
Andrew
-------------------------------------------
University of Minnesota
Minneapolis, MN 55455
odlyzko at umn.edu email
612-625-6413 voice phone
https://www-users.cse.umn.edu/~odlyzko
More information about the Nnagain
mailing list